Options and Futures
The Goal of financial engineering: Create financial instruments to meet various investment goals
The building ground: Uncertain stock price \(S_T\) representing the different realizations of the “state” of the world
The building blocks:
Stock | Bond | Call Option | Put Option | |
---|---|---|---|---|
Price | \(S_0\) | \(e^{-rT}\) | \(C_0\) | \(P_0\) |
Payoff at \(T\) | \(S_T\) | \(e^{rT}\) | \(\max\{\) \(S_T\) \(- K, 0\}\) | \(\max\{K -\) \(S_T\) \(, 0\}\) |
Profit at \(T\) | \(S_T\) \(-S_0 e^{rT}\) | \(0\) | \(\max\{\) \(S_T\) \(- K, 0\} -C_0 e^{rT}\) | \(\max\{K -\) \(S_T\) \(, 0\} -P_0 e^{rT}\) |
The role for engineers:
Buy a stock at \(S_0\) and borrow \(K e^{-rT}\)
Buy a call and short a put at the strike price \(K\)
\(+\)Call | \(-\)Put | Total | |
---|---|---|---|
\(S_T < K\) | \(0\) | \(K - S_T\) | \(S_T- K\) |
\(S_T \ge K\) | \(S_T - K\) | \(0\) | \(S_T - K\) |
Buy a forward contract with the delivery price \(K\)
Short-sell a stock at \(S_0\) and lend \(K e^{-rT}\)
Short a call and buy a put at the strike price \(K\)
\(-\)Call | \(+\)Put | Total | |
---|---|---|---|
\(S_T < K\) | \(0\) | \(K - S_T\) | \(K-S_T\) |
\(S_T \ge K\) | \(-(S_T - K)\) | \(0\) | \(K-S_T\) |
Short a forward contract with the delivery price \(K\)
Use Put-Call Parity: \[C = P + S_0 - K e^{-rT}\] we can recreate a call by long stock, short bond, and long put
Check the payoff:
Stock | Bond | Put | Total | |
---|---|---|---|---|
\(S_T < K\) | \(S_T\) | \(-K\) | \(K - S_T\) | \(0\) |
\(S_T \ge K\) | \(S_T\) | \(-K\) | \(0\) | \(S_T - K\) |
Exercise: Create a synthetic put
Covered Call: Sell the call and hedge it with the stock
Stock Price | \(40\) | \(60\) | \(80\) |
---|---|---|---|
Long Stock | \(40\) | \(60\) | \(80\) |
Short Call | \(0\) | \(0\) | \(-20\) |
Payoff | \(40\) | \(60\) | \(60\) |
Profit | \(-6.55\) | \(13.45\) | \(13.45\) |
Just like a put. In fact \[S_0 - C = K e^{-rT} - P\] It can be replicated by a put and a bond.
\[ \text{Profit} = \underset{\text{Payoff}}{\underbrace{\min\{S_T, K\}}} - \underset{\text{Cost}}{\underbrace{(S_0 - C_0) e^{rT}}} = 0 \]
Implication of No-Arbitrage Conditions
Suppose a portfolio have the price \(X\) and the payoff \(Y_T\) that is a random variable that have an upper bound \(\bar Y\) and a lower bound \(\underline Y\). Given the risk-free rate \(e^{rT}\), then we must have:
\[ \underline Y < X e^{rT} < \bar Y \]
cover a stock position with a put
Stock Price | \(30\) | \(50\) | \(70\) |
---|---|---|---|
Stock Payoff | \(30\) | \(50\) | \(70\) |
Stock profit | \(-20\) | \(0\) | \(20\) |
Payoff w/ Put | \(40\) | \(50\) | \(70\) |
Total Profit | \(-11.28\) | \(-1.28\) | \(18.72\) |
Straddle: Long call + Long put at the same \(K\)
First Welfare Theorem
Under complete markets, complete information and perfect competition, the market allocation is Pareto optimal.